News APP

NewsApp (Free)

Read news as it happens
Download NewsApp

Available on  gplay

Home  » Business » India's inflation: A macroeconomic mess

India's inflation: A macroeconomic mess

By Arvind Subramanian
June 27, 2008 10:04 IST
Get Rediff News in your Inbox:

Yes, we have a global inflation problem because world demand, especially for commodities, is running ahead of world capacity. The phenomenon is global but policy responses will be national.

So, which countries are going to act decisively to curtail demand? Of the three economically significant global players -- the US, EU, and China -- it is only the EU that has kept demand in check through relatively tight monetary policy.

The US and China have not. The US, in order to preserve its financial system and avoid a slow-down, has followed expansionary monetary and fiscal policies, aggravating global price pressures, and while China has tightened, it has been small in magnitude and done with reluctance because any serious slow down to the Chinese growth juggernaut is anathema to the Party.

What does this imply for India? While it is convenient, but no less accurate for that reason, to ascribe the origins of recent problem to external forces, Indian policy-makers have to move on. 

First, these external inflationary impulses are not going to be corrected externally: for reasons described above, neither the US nor China is going to act forcefully and quickly enough to provide relief for the average Indian consumer.

Moreover, we have moved to the second round, where the initial external supply shock has started affecting domestic prices across the board. In other words, we now have a domestic inflation problem which requires domestic policy action.

And yet, what have we seen?  Leave aside the obligatory and unhelpful tampering (trade and price controls) at the microeconomic level.

On the macro front, apart from the relatively modest hike in petroleum prices, the Indian policy response has been, well, somewhere between poor and awful, meriting a grade of about 2 out of 10.

Consider how fiscal, monetary and exchange rate policies have not just been inadequate, they have gone in the wrong direction.

The fiscal position is deteriorating, and substantially, at a time of accelerating inflation. One estimate is that the true central government fiscal deficit could deteriorate this year by a whopping 2.5-3 (at a minimum) percentage points of GDP thanks to a combination of the loan waivers, pay hikes, fertilizer subsidies, and above all, our automatic destabilisers.

By fixing retail prices for petroleum, government spending and the deficit automatically increase when oil prices rise, aggravating inflationary pressures. How sensible is that?

A lot has been written about petroleum pricing policy. Three points, however, bear repetition. Our petroleum pricing, like that of China, and the US, acts to maintain high world oil prices, and to turn the terms-of-trade against us.

This is self-inflicted harm, made worse by the fact that the beneficiaries of our policy are countries whose direct and indirect influence on us is far from benign.

Second, fixed retail prices are implemented in the name of equity and end up being bad not just for efficiency but also equity: petroleum consumers are richer than the average Indian, who pays for the consumption of the rich through a combination of higher taxes and/or inflation caused by oil subsidies.

But a third, and possibly important point as we look ahead relates to climate change. India, like other developing countries, justifiably rails against the rich world for having caused global warming. 

But we will simply not be a credible or cooperative global partner in the fight against this problem, and our legitimate complaints against the rich risk being dismissed as hypocrisy, if our policy contribution is to encourage rather than discourage fuel consumption. 

Monetary and exchange rate policies in these last few months have both been mystifyingly inadequate. In late February, a chorus of respected voices in India unanimously rounded upon the RBI for not lowering interest rates when the golden opportunity of US rate-cutting presented itself.

The RBI added considerably to its sheen by presciently citing the threat of inflationary pressures as the reason for its inaction. It was right and the commentators wrong.

Having displayed its anti-inflationary mettle then, it came as a surprise when in the period since mid-April, the RBI countenanced an exchange rate depreciation at a time of imported inflationary pressures.

To be fair, there has been some tightening of the CRR and repo rates, especially in the last few days.

But: (i) these have been small and delayed; (ii) the key reverse repo rate, which is arguably the real lever for the RBI to manipulate monetary conditions under conditions of excess liquidity, has remained unchanged at 6 per cent compared to current inflation of 11 per cent; and (iii) above all, combining the tepid monetary actions with the sizable rupee depreciation yields the conclusion that overall monetary conditions far from having tightened may actually be looser at a time of accelerating inflationary pressures.

The accompanying chart computes a simple monetary conditions index, and it is striking how prices and monetary policies have diverged in the recent past, and how even the most recent rate hikes may be inadequate to counter price pressures.

Thus, from an inflation perspective, we have destabilising rather than stabilising fiscal and monetary policies. There is a real mystery here because electoral populism cannot easily explain these policies; after all, high, especially double-digit, inflation is considered electorally fatal for incumbent politicians, and RBI policy-making has always reflected that political reality.

It is true that tightening will slow growth, but at 11 per cent inflation and 9 per cent growth, the politically expedient trade-off would have been to sacrifice some growth for lower inflation, especially since there is a plausible case that at 9 per cent growth we are testing the limits of the economy's capacity. Why aren't politicians behaving like politicians? Why is the RBI not being true to its inflation hawk credentials?

In India, political opportunism is ritually invoked to exonerate bad policies. In the current circumstances, even this cynical explanation seems inadequate. Good economics is proving elusive even when it is reasonable politics.

The author is Senior Fellow, Peterson Institute for International Economics and Center for Global Development, and Senior Research Professor, Johns Hopkins University. His book, India's Turn: Understanding the Economic Transformation (Oxford), has just been published

Get Rediff News in your Inbox:
Arvind Subramanian
Source: source
 

Moneywiz Live!